Other research summaries in this Reporter
NBER Reporter 2015 Number 2: Research Summary
The Economics of Happiness
John F. Helliwell
|
Measures of subjective well-being seemed like natural candidate measures of welfare. But to understand and assess their suitability required a broader disciplinary perspective. A useful starting point was to see if life satisfaction assessments from around the world supported Aristotle's prediction that people would report higher life satisfaction if they had better life circumstances, in the form of family, friends, good health, and sufficient material means, while also being supported from the one side by positive emotions and on the other by a sense of life purpose. Aristotle's presumptions were supported remarkably well by World Values Survey data, with two-level modeling revealing the joint importance of individual and national-level variables.4 The fact that life evaluations could be explained by income and other life circumstances permitted calculation of compensating differentials to compare the relative importance of different aspects of life.5
My subsequent work expanded the analysis to show that life evaluations depend more on the quality of government than on the institutions of democracy,6 especially when the former is at low levels, that workplace trust, as shown in the figure, is a very strong predictor of life satisfaction, even more so for women than men,7 and that the quality and quantity of social connections at work, at home, and in the neighborhood are perhaps the most important supports for life satisfaction.8
But what about suicide in those supposedly happy Scandinavian countries? A proper answer to this question required expertise from other disciplines. How well are modern international differences in suicide rates explained by the same factors exposed by Émile Durkheim's careful research more than a century ago?9 Can the same model consistently explain both life satisfaction and suicide rates? World Values Survey data showed that the same factors that had been found to be associated with international differences in life satisfaction were also associated with international differences in suicide rates, of course with the signs reversed. Sweden fit both models perfectly. Its very high subjective well-being and fairly average suicide rates were reconciled by the differing relative importance of some factor–such as divorce, religion, and government quality–between the suicide and life satisfaction models.10 Social trust and community connections were strongly and equally important in both models. Indeed, subsequent research suggested that higher levels of social trust were associated with significantly lower death rates from both suicides and traffic fatalities.11
The apparent usefulness of happiness data spurred deeper digging and a mixture of research methods to untangle two-way linkages between subjective well-being and other variables. It also led to research to establish the meaning and value of different ways of measuring subjective well-being,12 to assess the extent to which there are interpersonal and international differences in how happiness is measured and determined, to evaluate the extent to which the well-being effects of income and other factors depend on comparisons with others,13 and to use subjective well-being data to focus on the quality of economic development.14
Three recent sets of results invite special attention.

Life Evaluations versus Emotional Reports
The Power of Generosity
Marriage and the Set Point for Happiness
In a recent working paper,23 Shawn Grover and I explain the return to baseline by defining the comparison group closely. Although the individuals studied did indeed return to their pre-marriage levels of life satisfaction, they were still happier than they would have been without getting married, since most of the marriages were occurring at ages when the average life satisfaction was dropping, as part of a U-shaped age pattern of life satisfaction in many countries. In addition, the pre-marriage baseline was set too close to the point of marriage, thus already incorporating the happiness created when the long-term relationship was established with the eventual marriage not yet taken place. To be really convincing, however, our research needed to make full allowance for the reverse effects running from happiness to marriage. We did this by including each individual's measured life satisfaction several years in the past to capture any set point effect.
Finally, in attempting to find an explanation for the size and long duration of the happiness effects accompanying marriage in our U.K. sample, we took advantage of a question in another part of the survey asking each respondent to identify their best friend, with spouse or equivalent being one of the categories offered. The life satisfaction effects of being married, relative to being single, were always large and significant, and were more than 50 percent larger for those who reported their spouse as their best friend. The same relationship was also evident for the growing group who were living as a couple but not married–they were on average happier than the singles, but especially so if they regarded their partner as their best friend. Thus the research showed large and durable life satisfaction effects from a key change in life circumstances, reconciled the life-course and cross-sectional estimates, and developed evidence for a social and friendship-based basis for the well-being benefits of marriage. The paper thereby supports both the ability of life satisfaction measures to capture the well-being effects of changes in life circumstances and the importance of social factors in explaining levels and changes of life satisfaction.
1. R. A. Easterlin, "Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence," In P. A. David and M. W. Reder, eds., Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of Moses Abramovitz, New York, New York: Academic Press, 1974, pp. 89-125. ↩
2. J. F. Helliwell, "Empirical Linkages between Democracy and Economic Growth," NBER Working Paper No. 4066, May 1992, and British Journal of Political Science, 24(2), 1994, pp. 225-48. ↩
3. J. F. Helliwell and R. D. Putnam, "Economic Growth and Social Capital in Italy," Eastern Economic Journal, 21(3), 1995, pp. 295-307; and J. F. Helliwell "Economic Growth and Social Capital in Asia," NBER Working Paper No. 5570, February 1996, and in R. G. Harris, ed., The Asia-Pacific Region in the Global Economy: A Canadian Perspective, Calgary, Canada: University of Calgary Press, 1996, pp. 21-42. ↩
4. J. F. Helliwell, "How's Life? Combining Individual and National-Level Variables to Explain Subjective Well-Being," NBER Working Paper No. 9065, July 2002 and in Economic Modelling, 20(2), March 2003, pp. 331-60. ↩
5. J. F. Helliwell and C. P. Barrington-Leigh, "How Much is Social Capital Worth?" NBER Working Paper No. 16025, May 2010, and in J. Jetten, C. Haslam, and S. A. Haslam, eds., The Social Cure: Identity, Health and Well-Being, London, United Kingdom: Psychology Press, 2012, pp. 55-71. ↩
6. J. F. Helliwell and H. Huang, "How's Your Government? International Evidence Linking Good Government and Well-Being," NBER Working Paper 11988, January 2006, and British Journal of Political Science 38(4) , 2008, pp. 595-619. ↩
7. J. F. Helliwell and H. Huang, "Well-Being and Trust in the Workplace," NBER Working Paper 14589, December 2008, and Journal of Happiness Studies, 12(5), May 2011, pp. 747-67. ↩
8. J. F. Helliwell and R. D. Putnam, "The Social Context of Well-Being," Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London, Series B, Biological Sciences, 339(1499), 2004, pp. 1445-56. ↩
9. E. Durkheim, Le Suicide. tude de Sociologie, Paris, France: Félix Alcan, 1897. See also the English translation Suicide: A Study in Sociology [1897] by J.A. Spaulding and G. Simpson, Glencoe Ill., Free Press, 1951. ↩
10. J. F. Helliwell, "Well-Being and Social Capital: Does Suicide Pose a Puzzle?" NBER Working Paper No. 10896, November 2004, and Social Indicators Research, 81(3), May 2007, pp. 455-96. ↩
11. J. F. Helliwell and S. Wang, "Trust and Well-Being," NBER Working Paper No. 15911, April 2010, and International Journal of Wellbeing, 1(1), January 2011, pp. 42-78. ↩
12. J. F. Helliwell and C. P. Barrington-Leigh, "Measuring and Understanding Subjective Well-Being," NBER Working Paper No. 15887, April 2010, and Canadian Journal of Economics 43(3), August 2010, pp. 729-53. ↩
13. C. P. Barrington-Leigh and J. F. Helliwell, "Empathy and Emulation: Life Satisfaction and the Urban Geography of Comparison Groups," NBER Working Paper No. 14593, October 2008. See also J. F. Helliwell and H. Huang, "How's the Job? Well-Being and Social Capital in the Workplace," NBER Working Paper No. 11759, November 2005, and Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 63(2), 2010, pp. 225-28. ↩
14. J. F. Helliwell, "Life Satisfaction and Quality of Development," NBER Working Paper No. 14507, November 2008. Forthcoming in Policies for Happiness, Oxford University Press, edited by S. Bartolini, E.Bilancini, L. Bruni and P. Porta. ↩
15. J. F. Helliwell, C. P. Barrington-Leigh, A. Harris and H. Huang, "International Differences in the Social Context of Well-Being," NBER Working Paper No. 14720, February 2009, and in J. F. Helliwell, E. Diener and D. Kahneman, eds., International Differences in Well-Being, New York, New York: Oxford University Press, 2010, pp. 291-350. ↩
16. J. F. Helliwell and S. Wang, "Weekends and Subjective Well-Being," NBER Working Paper No. 17180, July 2011, and Social Indicators Research, 116(2), April 2014, pp. 389-407. ↩
17. See Table 2.1 of J. F. Helliwell and S. Wang, "World Happiness: Trends, Explanations and Distribution," in J. F. Helliwell, R. Layard and J. Sachs, eds., World Happiness Report 2013, New York, New York: United Nations Sustainable Development Solutions Network, September 2013. ↩
18. J. F. Helliwell and H. Huang, "New Measures of the Costs of Unemployment," NBER Working Paper No. 16829, February 2011, and in Economic Inquiry, 52(4), 2014, pp. 1485-1502. This paper shows that the spillover well-being losses of local unemployment on those still employed are in aggregate larger than the individual costs for the unemployed themselves. ↩
19. J. F. Helliwell, "Institutions as Enablers of Wellbeing: The Singapore Prison Case Study," International Journal of Wellbeing, 1(2), 2011, pp. 255-65. ↩
20. J. F. Helliwell, H. Huang, S. Grover and S. Wang, "Empirical Linkages Between Good Government and National Well-Being," NBER Working Paper No. 20686, November 2014. ↩
21. L. B. Aknin, C. P. Barrington-Leigh, E. Dunn, J. F. Helliwell, R. Biswas-Diener, I. Kemeza, P. Nyende, C. E. Ashton-James, M. Norton, "Prosocial Spending and Well-Being: Cross-Cultural Evidence for a Psychological Universal," NBER Working Paper No. 16415, September 2010, and Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 104(4), April 2013, pp. 635-52. ↩
22. L. B. Aknin, G. Mayraz, and J. F. Helliwell, "The Emotional Consequences of Donation Opportunities," NBER Working Paper No. 20696, November 2014. ↩
23. S. Grover and J. F. Helliwell, "How's Life at Home? New Evidence on Marriage and the Set Point for Happiness," NBER Working Paper No. 20794, December 2014. ↩